In Tuesday’s budget, NSW will announce a switch from stamp duty to land tax.
It will become the second Australian jurisdiction to do so, with the ACT halfway through a 20-year switchover.
Homebuyers who accept the offer will be taxed annually on the value of their land, instead of hit with an upfront fee (that averaged $50,000 for Sydney in 2018) when they buy.
Once they have accepted, their property will be out of the stamp duty system and subject only to land tax for future owners.
It’s become conventional wisdom to say that such a revenue-neutral switch would boost productivity.
Top Australian Brokers
- eToro - Social and copy trading platform - Read our review
- IC Markets - Experienced and highly regulated - Read our review
- Pepperstone - Trading education - Read our review
Why? Moving house sets in motion a chain of transactions: residents engage lawyers to transfer titles, real estate agents to manage the property sale, removalists to transport possessions, and so on.
Stamp duties compound these costs, by adding a significant, additional layer of taxation, which in some states makes up 80% of the total cost of moving house.
Land tax, in contrast, is one of the least-damaging taxes. It encourages land owners to put land to its highest-value use.
In a landmark modelling exercise completed this month, my team at the Victoria University Centre of Policy Studies finds that the productivity gains are large by the standards of tax swaps.
After 20 years, replacing stamp duty with a land tax would boost national income by A$0.30 for each dollar of revenue swapped, or up to $720 per household if implemented Australia-wide, about 0.34% of annual gross domestic product.
Of greater interest for homeowners and buyers is what it would do to prices.
Houses versus apartments
Broadly, we find that the switch would put downward pressure on prices, but not for every type of home.
Across the market as a whole, we expect downward pressure on the price paid by buyers of about 4.7%, and downward pressure on the price received by sellers of about 0.1%.
But for houses, we expect much stronger downward pressure than the average suggests.
We expect the price paid by house buyers to fall by about 7.6%, and the price received by sellers to fall 3%.
Interestingly, for apartments we expect movements in the other direction, pushing up the price paid by buyers by 2%, and pushing up the price received by sellers by 6.4%.
What’s so different about apartments?
Why would the switch put downward pressure on the price of houses but upward pressure on the price of apartments?
It is because of how two offsetting effects play out.
One is that higher land taxes depress land prices. Buyers who know they will be lumbered with future bills find their purchases less valuable. This effect is much bigger on house prices than apartment prices, because houses occupy more land on average.
The other effect is that removing stamp duty not only removes an impost on the current buyer, but also removes an impost that will have to be paid when the current buyer sells, and when the subsequent buyer sells, and so on, making resale more valuable to the current buyer than it would have been.
For properties that aren’t turned over often this effect isn’t very important, but for properties that are turned over frequently, it becomes significant.
Apartments are turned over twice as frequently as houses, meaning that for apartments the upward effect on prices from removing stamp duty overwhelms the downward effect from imposing land tax.
Much depends on exactly what’s proposed
It would be possible to lessen this upward pressure on apartment prices by imposing higher land taxes on higher density housing, an idea canvassed by the Henry Tax Review in 2010. Planning and zoning rules could also play a role.
Other policy design decisions could have other effects on prices. Our modelling is based on an immediate swap of stamp duty for land tax.
This is not the same as the NSW government’s opt-in proposal, which could have different price consequences to the policy we modelled.
The NSW government is also reported to be considering excluding the most expensive 20% of properties from the switchover, so it can continue to collect stamp duties on high-value transfers.
In future work we plan to extend our modelling beyond a simple swap of stamp duty and land tax.
Originally published by The Conversation
Jason Nassios – Associate Professor, Centre of Policy Studies, Victoria University
James Giesecke – Professor, Centre of Policy Studies and the Impact Project, Victoria University